Walmart pay rise is great but raising the US minimum wage is not the best way to reduce inequality
In the US, Walmart is giving more than a million of its employees a raise in February as part of a plan to provide all but its newest staff with at least $10 (£6.90) an hour. The move, announced last year, follows an aggressive campaign to get the largest private employer in the US to increase worker wages and coincides with a nationwide push to raise federal and state minimum wages and a prolonged period of little growth in pay.
While Walmart's decision is at least in part a result of that pressure, it's still the action of a private company to revamp its own wage policies as opposed to the result of a government forcing it to increase worker pay. Proponents of requiring just that argue that raising the minimum helps to reduce inequality. Critics contend that it can actually worsen it by driving up unemployment and weakening economywide labour-market flexibility by raising the costs that firms face.
So what does the economic research say about the impact of minimum wages on income inequality and is there a better way to reduce it?
The fallacies about minimum wage
Many of the articles in the mainstream press promoting minimum wages are incompatible with basic economic principles. The first fallacy is that changes in the minimum wage do not affect the behavioral response among firms and individuals. The second fallacy is that higher wages force companies to innovate in order to reduce costs. Both these arguments overlook some very basic yet informative economic principles.
The first overlooks the fact that wages are designed to compensate workers for productivity. When wages are distorted, they affect the profit-maximising decisions that businesses make. The textbook prediction, which is generally supported in data, is that higher minimum wages reduce employment since companies restrict the number of workers they hire. These adverse effects are especially likely, given the pace of technological change and automation.
The second overlooks the fact that there are effective and ineffective ways to stimulate innovation among businesses. The idea that making hiring more costly will spur innovation is tantamount to requiring companies to reduce the size of their physical presence so they become more productive. While these types of distortions may prompt a small fraction of companies to innovate, misallocation more generally is a major factor behind cross-country differences in productivity.
Minimum wage and inequality
Nonetheless, economists themselves have debated how minimum wages affect employer decisions for many years. In 1994, economists David Card and Alan Krueger were the first to provide evidence that such effects may be small. More recently, a consensus has emerged that changes to minimum wages strongly effects jobs growth.
How minimum wages affect inequality is controversial. Detecting it with standard methods is very challenging because their full effects are constantly changing and require data on both individuals and companies. In 1999, Princeton economist David Lee used the Consumer Population Survey (CPS) from 1979 to 1989 to argue that the declining purchasing power of the minimum wage largely explains why inequality surged in the 1980s.
Other new research, however, has put that conclusion in doubt. Perhaps the most conclusive reassessment comes from economists David Autor, Alan Manning and Christopher Smith earlier this year. Using many more years of microdata from the CPS, as well as a different statistical approach, they found that the minimum wage explains at most 30-40% of the rise in wage inequality among the lowest earners.
Since economists had thought that changes in the minimum wage could explain as much as 90% of the shift in inequality, these new estimates are important.
How wages affect worker behaviour
While the extent is still uncertain, it's clear that the minimum wage and other wage-setting forces such as tax rates and union bargaining power do in fact affect inequality and the labour market. My own ongoing research, which focuses on the link between such wage-setting mechanisms and company behaviour, suggests labour-market distortions such as raising the minimum wage can have other negative effects on workers, businesses and inequality beyond the overall impact on employment.
The first adverse effect concerns how much people work. If, for example, worker wages rise due to a government mandate, the employer may reduce the number of hours that staff work, leading to lower paycheques even after the raise. That's part of the reason why we've seen companies such as McDonald's increasingly try to automate tasks that were once held by people. In addition, my research suggests one of the major ways that people acquire new skills is by spending more time at work. Thus policies that lead to fewer hours could lower employees' ability to improve their long-run earnings potential.
The second is an indirect effect on the way businesses invest in workers and design compensation and organisational policies. When companies are forced to pay higher wages, they may offset the cost by reducing how much they invest in workers. There is evidence that minimum-wage laws have this effect. This can result in weaker compensation contracts (for example, purely salary-based), which provide employees with fewer incentives to accumulate skills. As a result, workers paid fixed wages suffer greater long-run earnings volatility than those receiving performance-based pay.
Put simply, if a recession comes and an individual loses his or her job, having more skills makes it easier to find a new position and return to the previous income level.
Minimal impact on inequality
Even setting aside all the plausible economic arguments against the minimum wage, under the best-case scenario, what does it really achieve? If the average full-time employee in the US works 1,700 hours a year, then moving from $7.25 to $9 an hour produces only around $2,975 in additional annual earnings. While some may argue that something is better than nothing, this would be at best a marginal solution to inequality.
Taking a look at the most recent 2015 Current Population Survey data and restricting the sample to full-time earners with over $10,000 earnings per year, Americans at the 90th income percentile (they earn more than 90 percent of their compatriots, or $80,000 a year) make 5.6 times as much, on average, as those at the 10th percentile ($14,200). Increasing the minimum wage to $9 an hour would put the ratio around 4.65.
In other words, even in the best of worlds – where the minimum wage has no unintended side effects – it appears to only marginally reduce inequality.
Alternatives to raising the minimum wage
Where does this leave us in trying to reduce inequality?
First, companies are welcome to raise wages at any time they want. And letting them do so may be more effective at reducing inequality than when they're forced to because it avoids the adverse consequences such as reducing hours.
Businesses are well aware of their marginal costs and benefits – how much it costs to produce an additional unit of output versus the incremental gain. When governments set uniform wage regulations, they require all companies – each with their own and distinct marginal costs and benefits – to abide by the same rules. In contrast, when companies decide to change their own pay practices, as Walmart is doing, they do so in a more efficient way.
Second, as Stanford economist John Cochrane has remarked, instead of addressing the short-term problem of low wages, governments and companies can address the more structural problem: a lack of skills.
Companies and local governments can provide training programmes and support for additional education, such as through community colleges, in order to equip workers with additional skills that translate into meaningful value for their companies. Investing in worker skills can lead to increased employee productivity and creativity, which in turn translates into sustained higher wages. And these benefits have broad spillover effects throughout the labour market and make sustainable gains in narrowing the gap between the richest and the poorest.
While the economic effects of minimum wage laws are very complex and a subject of scrutiny within the economics community, there are much better ways to deal with systematic challenges in the labour market. Getting more people to work, reducing the barriers for businesses to hire and encouraging the accumulation of new skills are all strategies for promoting sustainable long-term growth in wages.
Christos Makridis is a PhD candidate in Macroeconomics and Public Finance at Stanford University in California, the US
This article was originally published on The Conversation. Read the original article here
© Copyright IBTimes 2024. All rights reserved.